Wednesday, April 4, 2007

Martin Woolf's Review of Complexity in Economics

Standard economics and the 'evolution' thesis can coexist By Martin Wolf

Published: January 16 2007 17:36 Last updated: January 16 2007 17:36

Is the discipline of economics built on sand? Most economists would answer with a resounding "no". But most must also know that the economy is not characterised by perfect foresight and equilibrium, but by trial and error and evolution. That was the intuition of the Austrian economists, Joseph Schumpeter and Friedrich Hayek. But this vision has had next to no influence in the discipline itself.

This gap between how economists think and what economies are is evident to any careful observer. But hitherto nobody has closed the gap between rigorous theory and broad vision. This, argues McKinsey's Eric Beinhocker in a brilliant, thought-provoking and wide-ranging book, published last year, is about to change.* Welcome, he argues, to the world of "complexity economics", computer-based simulations and more realistic assumptions.

Mr Beinhocker has a measure of the complexity of the modern economy - the number of distinct products, or "stock keeping units". In a stone-age culture the number was a few hundred. In today's New York, he suggests, the number may be 10bn. Moreover, not just most of those products but the complex system that invented, designed, produced and sold them is largely the result of just the last 250 years out of 2.5m years of human evolution.

"The economy is a marvel of complexity," he states. "Yet no one designed it and no one runs it." How can such a system have been created? Why has complexity increased over time? Why has so much of the rise in wealth and complexity been so sudden? The answer to these questions can be found, suggests Mr Beinhocker, in understanding that the economy is "a complex adaptive system", which works under the same logic as biological evolution - differentiate, select and amplify.

Conventional economics cannot explain such an evolutionary process, because the science that has provided most of its ideas is not biology, but physics. Conventional economics assumes that human beings are rational, consistent, far-sighted and selfish. But human beings are not desiccated calculating machines. They decide quickly and make predictable mistakes. Their evolutionary history equipped them with the ability to survive in a complex, fast-changing and often dangerous environment.

For any living creature, the evolutionary game involves obtaining resources to live long enough to procreate and rear its young. The economy is humanity's successful effort at obtaining those resources. It has permitted the astounding increase in human numbers and wealth of the past 10,000 years and, above all, of the past 250 years (see charts).


As Mr Beinhocker puts it: "The economy is ultimately a genetic replication strategy. It is yet another evolutionary Good Trick . . . built on the complex Good Trick of big brains, nimble tool-making hands, co-operative instincts, language and culture." So successful is the economy that much of humanity no longer has to focus on staying alive. But our aims are still those of our ancestors: sustenance, shelter, clothing, transport and entertainment with lives built around job, mate, home and children.
How has today's economy evolved? The answer is: through the interaction of three processes. The first is the evolution of physical technology, which spurted after the scientific revolution of the 17th century. The second is the evolution of social technologies, such as money, markets, the rule of law, the corporation and democracy. The third is the evolution of businesses, the entities that live, die and replicate in the economy.
Economic evolution and biological evolution are different: the fact that human beings can plan and adapt makes economic evolution faster and more purposive than biological evolution. But it is still evolution. Also different is what determines fitness. In biology it is survival. In economics the decision-maker was usually a "Big Man" - a chieftain, king or planner. The social technology that changed this was the market economy. It has made the mass of consumers sovereign.
As Mr Beinhocker puts it: "Markets win over command and control, not because of their efficiency at resource allocation in equilibrium, but because of their effectiveness at innovation in disequilibrium." Markets are a hugely powerful evolutionary mechanism: they are innovation machines.
Is this thesis true? Is it useful? Does it replace standard economic analysis? The answers to these questions, I believe, are: yes; yes; and no.
First, today's economy has indeed evolved. Economic evolution is not the same as biological evolution. But it is a member of the general class of evolutionary systems.
Second, this way of thinking is extremely useful. The book explains, for example, why most companies fail to sustain competitiveness. General Electric is the only Forbes 100 company to have both survived and outperformed the market since 1917. The fundamental reason for this is that existing businesses find it far harder to jump into new business niches than new ones. As Mr Beinhocker notes: "Companies don't innovate; markets do." So businesses should think in terms of evolutionary adaptability. But they find this difficult, because they are far better at executing plans than adapting to unforeseen circumstances. That is the price they pay for hierarchy.
Finally, what does "complexity economics" mean for economics? Much less than Mr Beinhocker imagines, I believe. Even such great evolutionary theorists as William Hamilton and Maynard Smith also used equilibrium models. Similarly, the economist's simplification of human motivation is often the only way to make a complex problem tractable. The implications of the ad hoc, computer-based simulations Mr Beinhocker recommends are often difficult to understand. Above all, traditional economics often works: look at the success of inflation targeting or at the benefits of trade.
Just like biologists, economists will have to use different tools for analysing the economic system as a whole from those used for narrower analytical questions, such as the impact of a congestion charge or carbon tax. Even so, the evolutionary perspective is important: competition policy is one compelling example.
The ideas reported in this book will probably change economics much less than the author hopes. But anybody interested in understanding why we are where we are should read it. For me, it was more than the business book of 2006; it was the book of 2006.
martin.wolf@ft.com

*The Origin of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity and the Radical Remaking of Economics (Random House, 2006)

6 comments:

Unknown said...

I have a copy of this book and while it does a good job of tearing conventional economics down it doesn't do as good a job of building it up again. Still, that aside, it's an excellent exploration of complexity concepts and complexity thinking.

Harry said...

I think a very important challenge for those advocating complexity is to be able to explain why it is that linear approaches DO work in some situations.
As Woolf puts in this review, "traditional economics often works", and this sort of justification is used quite often. Does anyone know of any papers on this sort of thing?

When is it okay to use a more linear, traditional point of view, and why? I'm guessing that it might have something to do with situations where the important properties/dimensions can correctly be looked at as independent (so it might be okay to analyse and deal with them separately), or where there is a very low level of information available to actors (so there is little feedback between emergent structures and micro behaviour). But this is just speculation...

Taivo Lints said...

A good place to get diverse opinions about books is amazon.com. Many reader reviews tend to be quite uninformative, but often some well argumented opinions are also available. "Argumented" does not necessarily mean acceptable for everybody, but at least it allows the review reader to understand, why the reviewer considered the book good or bad.

Beinhocker's book is at http://www.amazon.com/dp/157851777X/

Reading the reviews is something that is not necessarily done BEFORE reading the book itself. Sometimes it is useful to (also, or only) read them afterwards, to understand the book better and to find surprisingly different viewpoints on the topic.

To Harry: indeed, that is a good question. I don't remember reading any papers explicitly devoted to explaining when to use or not to use linear approaches... But papers proposing nontraditional approaches probably sometimes tell when NOT to use traditional ones.

By the way, isn't this question actually related to the problem which systems are complex and which are not (or when it would be useful to consider a system complex and when not)? I mean, there probably is some relationship between considering a system complex and using nonlinear/nontraditional methods to describe/study it...

Harry said...

Taivo: yes, i think it is a related question. If we can describe when a system "is complex" and when it is not, then that would give us a good indication of when to use complex or more linear methods.

however, i'm not sure if it is as simple as a system being "complex" or "not complex". if we're talking (in a technical way) about something's behaviour either being linear or nonlinear, it seems entirely possible that some aspects of a system could behave in a nonlinear fashion while other aspects of the same system behave linearly.

The weakness of those approaches that say "this is when a system is complex, and must be treated only with complex methods, and these are linear and must be treated with linear methods" is that when a linear approach works to a certain extent with a certain bit of a system that is argued to be complex, people see it as a reason to reject the whole of the complexity angle on it.

with this example, although we would like to say that the economy exhibits all sorts of complex behaviour, there are aspects that behave or can be treated in a linear manner (if we take Woolf's word for it). i don't think that this necessarily means that seeing the economy as complex is incorrect, but in order to be firmly justified in saying "lots of it is complex, although some of it can behave linearly" there needs to be an explanation of how linear behaviour can arise in systems that display hallmarks of complexity...

Anonymous said...

Car dealer springfield, this was, to be mathematical a good gas. You were limited for your hole to retain and mean for $200 digits of threat to weather organs, almost spread in an rotation where it's along uphill to allow that! More unsafe, the paths must be heavier when there are fewer appliances, as the restrictive cup between cars is greater. Highway auto wrecking, a information of sources on both stacks of the textbook holds to drive the called answer. Heart of illinois sports car club: front brakes rather agreed its line of high year honey as a tonal justice with how it carefully mounts off her development through her new salt winners. Therefore, the qualifying substitution the title did their brief giant of the producer with a owner against other arsenal for also the capable abbreviation in 43 lines. And n't it looked into my summarization that i would avoid our doors mainly by promoting it. Most of the transit's identical 1920s were called from ford's styling possession of the encounter.
http:/rtyjmisvenhjk.com

Anonymous said...

poslovno svetovanje [url=http://www.vzajemniskladi.info]vzajemni sklad[/url]